http://rmid-oecd.asean.org/situs slot gacorlink slot gacorslot gacorslot88slot gacorslot gacor hari inilink slot gacorslot88judi slot onlineslot gacorsitus slot gacor 2022https://www.dispuig.com/-/slot-gacor/https://www.thungsriudomhospital.com/web/assets/slot-gacor/slot88https://omnipacgroup.com/slot-gacor/https://viconsortium.com/slot-online/http://soac.abejor.org.br/http://oard3.doa.go.th/slot-deposit-pulsa/https://www.moodle.wskiz.edu/http://km87979.hekko24.pl/https://apis-dev.appraisal.carmax.com/https://sms.tsmu.edu/slot-gacor/http://njmr.in/public/slot-gacor/https://devnzeta.immigration.govt.nz/http://ttkt.tdu.edu.vn/-/slot-deposit-dana/https://ingenieria.unach.mx/media/slot-deposit-pulsa/https://www.hcu-eng.hcu.ac.th/wp-content/uploads/2019/05/-/slot-gacor/https://euromed.com.eg/-/slot-gacor/http://www.relise.eco.br/public/journals/1/slot-online/https://research.uru.ac.th/file/slot-deposit-pulsa-tanpa-potongan/http://journal-kogam.kisi.kz/public/journals/1/slot-online/https://aeeid.asean.org/wp-content/https://karsu.uz/wp-content/uploads/2018/04/-/slot-deposit-pulsa/https://zfk.katecheza.radom.pl/public/journals/1/slot-deposit-pulsa/https://science.karsu.uz/public/journals/1/slot-deposit-pulsa/ {"id":9388,"date":"2019-04-02T19:37:41","date_gmt":"2019-04-02T16:37:41","guid":{"rendered":"http:\/\/qje.su\/?p=9388"},"modified":"2019-04-02T19:37:49","modified_gmt":"2019-04-02T16:37:49","slug":"moskovskij-ekonomicheskij-zhurnal-4-2019-9","status":"publish","type":"post","link":"https:\/\/qje.su\/en\/otraslevaya-i-regionalnaya-ekonomika\/moskovskij-ekonomicheskij-zhurnal-4-2019-9\/","title":{"rendered":"\u041c\u043e\u0441\u043a\u043e\u0432\u0441\u043a\u0438\u0439 \u044d\u043a\u043e\u043d\u043e\u043c\u0438\u0447\u0435\u0441\u043a\u0438\u0439 \u0436\u0443\u0440\u043d\u0430\u043b 4\/2019"},"content":{"rendered":"
\"image_pdf\"<\/a>\"image_print\"<\/a><\/div>\n
\"\"<\/figure><\/div>\n\n\n\n

\u0423\u0414\u041a<\/strong>:\n[338.246.2:001.895] = 111 <\/strong><\/p>\n\n\n\n

DOI 10.24411\/2413-046\u0425-2019-14008<\/strong><\/p>\n\n\n\n

Innovations\nand prospects for the innovative development of the economy in the Russian\nFederation<\/strong><\/p>\n\n\n\n

Mogilevich Ekaterina, Semenov Dmitriy, <\/strong>Financial University under the Government of the\nRussian Federation, Moscow<\/p>\n\n\n\n

Scientific advisor,\nSenior teacher Moiseeva<\/strong> T.V.<\/strong><\/p>\n\n\n\n

Summary: <\/strong>The article reveals the essence of innovation performance and its economic implications which ensure a long-term steady growth of the nation\u2019s welfare, labor productivity, as well as the country’s success in competing for major positions in global markets, as well as the necessary factors for ensuring and implementing the economic growth, creating\u00a0 favorable environment conditions to innovation and correcting prioritization by areas of innovation policy support.<\/p>\n\n\n\n

Key words: <\/strong>\u00a0innovation policy, innovation potential, labor productivity, employment, human capital, innovation pyramid, capital-labor ratio, economic growth, economic well-being, technological development.<\/p>\n\n\n\n

The economic theory contains many fundamental works which show that\nlong-term economic growth is determined not only by an increase in production\nfactors, but also by technological innovations. Based on these works, four main\nlevers of influence on the long-term growth (15-20 years) of economic\nwell-being can be identified: the growth of employment; innovation\n(productivity growth); improving the quality of labor (increase in labor\nproductivity); growth of capital-labor ratio (increase in labor productivity).\nThe term “innovation” comes from the Latin “novatio”, which\nmeans “update” (or “change”), and the prefix\n“in”, which is translated from Latin as “in the direction”,\nif translated literally.  [1, P. 231.]<\/p>\n\n\n\n

“Innovatio” – “towards change”. The concept of\n\u201cinnovation\u201d first appeared in nineteenth-century research. The concept of\n“innovation” received  a new\nlife in the beginning of the XX century in the scientific works of the Austrian\nand American economist J. Schumpeter as a result of the analysis of\n“innovative combinations”, changes in the development of economic\nsystems. Schumpeter was one of the first scientists who, in the 1900s. put this\nterm into scientific use in economics. Innovation is not any  innovation, but only one that seriously\nincreases the efficiency of the current system. Now innovations are the main\npossible levers of influence on the long-term growth of economic well-being for\nRussia, since it is possible for three other of the four available to be significantly\nlimited: for employment – there is a rapid decline in the number of working-age\npopulation; for the quality of the workforce \n– a deterioration of the situation is predicted as a result of a weak\nstate policy, for capital-labor ratio \u2013 because of  an outflow of capital, there is no stock on\nthe level of capacity utilization of the economy. The possibility of long-term\neconomic growth through innovations, especially in the countries that are not\nleaders in innovations, has long been noted in the economic theory and\nconfirmed by macroeconomic data for Russia, China and South Korea over the past\n20 years.<\/p>\n\n\n\n

The main levers of growth of\neconomic well-being.<\/strong>\nEconomic theory contains many fundamental works showing that a long-term economic\ngrowth is determined not only by an increase in production factors, but also by\ntechnological innovations. A longer-term growth in economic well-being,\nmeasured as GDP growth per capita, is determined in more detail by two factors\n(see Fig. 1): employment growth and productivity growth. In turn, the growth of\nlabor productivity, based on the model of a long-term growth R. Solow (1957),\nconsists of three components: the growth of total factor productivity (Total\nfactor productivity, then TFP is a widely accepted paradigm for estimating and\nforecasting long-term production dynamics) as changes in TFP reflect changes in\nGDP that are not explained by changes in production factors); the growth of the\nquality of the workforce (worker skills); growth of capital-labor ratio\n(available capital per employee). The change in total factor productivity is\ncalculated as a change in GDP, not explained by changes in the factors of\nproduction (labor and capital), and in the long-term horizon is mainly due to\ninnovations.<\/p>\n\n\n\n

So, based on the factors determining the growth of well-being, and the ability to influence their changes, we can distinguish four main levers of influence on the long-term growth of economic well-being (see Fig. 1): the growth of employment; innovation (productivity growth); improving the quality of labor (increase in labor productivity); growth of capital-labor ratio (increase in labor productivity).<\/p>\n\n\n\n

\"\"<\/figure><\/div>\n\n\n\n

Sources of growth of economic well-being in Russia.<\/strong> Let us consider in more detail the current\npossibilities of enhancing the economic well-being for Russia. The first lever\n– the growth of employment of the population – is not able to provide a\nsignificant increase in economic well-being due to the current and projected\ndynamics of demographic indicators. Thus, the number of working-age population\nis rapidly decreasing since 2006, and it is projected that by 2020 it will be\n80.6 million people, which is about 10 million less than in 2006. [2; p 561]\n\nThe other three\nlevers – innovation, quality of work force and capital-labor ratio – directly\nincrease the productivity. Let’s look at the dynamics and absolute levels of\nthis indicator in Russia and developed countries. Labor productivity in Russia,\nhaving shown a significant increase (by 60%) from 2000 to 2014, has practically\nnot increased in the last three years (see Fig. 2). At the same time, the lag\nof Russia in labor productivity from most developed countries remains\nsubstantial. Thus, the average labor productivity in the first ten of the\nleading countries in this indicator is 2.8 times more than in Russia.\n\n\n\n<\/p>\n\n\n\n

\"\"<\/figure><\/div>\n\n\n\n

\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\nA significant lag in the labor productivity is\nobserved in all sectors, with the exception of the extractive sector of the\neconomy (see Fig. 3). Particular attention should be paid to the fact that\nhigh-tech products, being the main driver of high performance in developed\ncountries, are the most problematic industries for Russia.\n\n\n\n<\/p>\n\n\n\n

\"\"<\/figure><\/div>\n\n\n\n

The third lever –\nimproving the quality of labor – is unlikely to be the source of a significant\nincrease in the labor productivity due to the significant inertia and moderate\ndynamics of this indicator in the past few years. The main factors determining\nthe quality of the workforce are the education and experience of the working\npopulation. Weak state policies in the field of education in the 1990s and the\nimpossibility of completely replacing the retiring experienced working-age\npopulation only worsen the forecast for the dynamics of the quality of the\nlabor force in Russia.<\/p>\n\n\n\n

The fourth lever –  an increase in\nthe capital-to-use ratio –  also does not\nhelp to reduce a significant gap in the labor productivity, because the net\ncapital outflow since 2008 is in the range of 2\u20134% of GDP, or 10\u201320% of the\nannual capital investment in economics [8; P.342-343]; the financial ability to support investments by the\nstate is significantly limited (for example, the total amount of the Reserve\nFund and the National Wealth Fund is 23% of the annual volume of annual capital\ninvestments in the economy) [4, P.282]; capacity\nutilization in the economy is approximately 67%, which is very close to the\nmaximum value over the past 20 years, equal to 73% (estimated, the load in a normal\noperation can be up to 82%).<\/p>\n\n\n\n

As it can be seen, the long-term growth of the economic well-being in\nRussia, now due to the three examined levers – the growth of employment of the\npopulation, the growth of the quality of the labor force and the growth of the\ncapital-labor ratio, is very limited. So, the only opportunity for a\nsignificant increase in wealth for Russia now is innovations.<\/p>\n\n\n\n

Economic growth through\ninnovation.<\/strong> The\npossibility of long-term economic growth through innovations, especially in\ncountries that are not leaders in innovations, has long been confirmed in the\neconomic literature. It is argued that as soon as a society opens up for mutual\neconomic exchange with technology leaders, a fairly rapid process of reducing\nthe backlog through diffusion of advanced innovations begins to take place. It\nis noted that this process serves as the main driver of the economic growth.\n\nThis statement has\nbeen confirmed by macroeconomic data for Russia, China and South Korea over the\npast 20 years (see Fig. 4). Thus, a substantial part of the economic growth of\n25\u201350% in these countries accounts for the growth of the total factor\nproductivity, that is, mainly due to the product, process, marketing and\norganizational innovations. [5; P.\n121-155]\n\n\n\n<\/p>\n\n\n\n

\"\"<\/figure><\/div>\n\n\n\n

\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\n\nA significant increase in the total factor\nproductivity in Russia in the period from 1995 to 2009 was primarily ensured by\ninnovations in  the financial sector,\nreal estate operations, production of electrical, electronic and optical\nequipment, production of rubber and plastic products, textile and clothing industry,\nproduction leather products and footwear (see Fig. 5).\n\n\n\n<\/p>\n\n\n\n

\"\"<\/figure><\/div>\n\n\n\n

Thus, Russia has demonstrated a significant increase in total factor\nproductivity in most sectors of the economy over the last 15\u201320 years, and  a  significant lag in the labor productivity\nindicates further opportunities for the long-term growth in the economic\nwell-being.The pyramid of innovation development<\/strong>. For the growth and\ndevelopment of innovations in the country, it is necessary to have a favorable\nenvironment for scientists, entrepreneurs and innovators. This widely\nrecognized and popular thesis is formulated in strategic documents of almost\nall countries that have reached a high level of an innovative development. The\nRussian state strategy of development, adopted in 2011, also pays a great\nattention to the topic of providing a favorable innovative environment.\n\n\n\n<\/p>\n\n\n\n

\"\"<\/figure>\n\n\n\n

In this report we\nwant to go a step ahead  and, first, to\nreveal in more detail the very concept of the medium – to show what elements it\nconsists of and how it is structured, and secondly, turn the thesis about the priority\nof a favorable environment into quantitative analytical tool that could be used\nin the  policy of innovations. We propose\nto structure the concept of the environment in the form of a pyramid of an innovative\ndevelopment, or shortly – the pyramid of innovations. This pyramid, by analogy\nwith Maslow’s pyramid, defines the hierarchical sequence of the needs of the\ninnovations environment. These needs, in turn, determine the main blocks of\nstate policy instruments and their priorities (see Fig. 6).<\/p>\n\n\n\n

Please, also note that we have drawn  an analogy between the theme of innovations\nand  that \nof  the football. You can find a\ncolumn entitled \u201cAnalogs with football\u201d. The football allegory will help to\nrelate the highly specialized theme of innovations to the theme of the struggle\nfor the world leadership in football, one way or another understandable to most\nof us, the football fever that has engulfed the world in recent decades looks\nlike an innovative fever, no state can afford to stay away. In football, as in\ninnovations, that player is good who \ndoes  not only scores, but scores\nmore than others, that team is good, which is not only famous for traditions or\nnames, but wins in the current championships and the country cannot be\nconsidered a football country whose team has not participated in the final\ngames of the world championship for a long time – whatever the circumstances.  They prevented the game, but then how can we\nwin the World Cup? We have seen different  solutions all over the world, including inviting\na dear foreign coach, giving citizenship and money to high-class foreign\nplayers. and so on, but no coach will teach a team that has no talented\nplayers, no legionaries will be able to firmly establish the country in the\nlist of football powers, and the only way – difficult, long and ungrateful for\ncurrent football functionaries – is to create  good football traditions and facilities in the\ncountry, that is a favorable  environment:\ninfrastructure, schools, clubs, game culture, fans, related business. And to\nmake it all better than in Brazil, Germany, Spain, Italy and so on.<\/p>\n\n\n\n

In addition to providing a favorable environment, an important component\nof innovations policy is also to direct financial support for research and\ninnovative projects. This type of policy is attractive for the state, because\nit is concrete, measurable, promises fast positive results and makes available  a pool of “wards” to the state.\nCreating the environment is a long process, poorly structured and not having a\nspecific recipe.<\/p>\n\n\n\n

However, only by providing a favorable environment, the state can expect\ndirect support to be effective. In this case, firstly, the projects themselves\nwill appear that did not grow in the hostile environment, and secondly – the\nchannels of an effective distribution of funds. Thus, if the principle of the\npyramid is applied to the \u201cenvironment\u201d and \u201cfinancing\u201d blocks, the first one\nshould be placed in the \u201cfoundation\u201d, and the second – on the \u201cupper floors\u201d\n(see Fig. 6).<\/p>\n\n\n\n

The state of innovations in\nRussia.<\/strong> The development of\nthe innovative  sphere in Russia can be\ndivided into two stages. Until 2014, the state\u2019s efforts were mostly aimed at\ncreating basic elements of the innovative infrastructure, developing the\nprofessional competencies of the system\u2019s participants, encouraging the\ndevelopment of new promising markets and supporting innovative projects,\nreorganizing the scientific sphere and developing state programs aimed at\ndevelopment of high-tech sectors of the economy.  Now, there is a stage of rethinking the\nfunctioning of the current system. In the framework of the execution of the\nlist of instructions D.A. Medvedev on the development of innovations from\n09.08.14, the central projects for the development of the innovation system are\nincreasing the efficiency of government bodies, promoting the development of\ncompanies with state participation and private business, further developing and\nincreasing the efficiency of the system of research and development  institutions. The priorities for the present\ntime  are the analysis of innovative\nprograms of state-owned companies, the assessment of R & D  institutions, investment in research and\nimprovement of the R & D base (research, development and civil engineering\nwork carried out by in the framework of a complex project), national projects\nwith a high innovative components. Among the main results, there are the development\nof competences on the economic growth, the adoption of the Federal Law of\nDecember 29, 2012 No. 273-FZ \u201cOn Education in the Russian Federation\u201d the  launch of practice-oriented undergraduate\n(applied  Bachelors ) programs, as well\nas dual education programs, oriented on training in the conditions of real\nproduction and taking into account modern professional standards.<\/p>\n\n\n\n

The development of science (pyramid layer – knowledge) includes  the implementation of the reorganization of\nstate academies of sciences, the creation of the Federal Agency for Scientific\nOrganizations, the Russian Science Foundation and the Advanced Research\nFoundation, the approval of the Program of the fundamental scientific research\nin the Russian Federation for a long \nperiod, the  approval of the\nForecast of scientific and technological development of the Russian Federation\nfor the period up to 2030.<\/p>\n\n\n\n

The infrastructure development (pyramid layer – infrastructure) consists\nof the development of state programs of the Russian Federation \u201cEconomic\ndevelopment and innovative economy\u201d, \u201cDevelopment of science and technologies\u201d,\n\u201cDevelopment of the industry and increase of its competitiveness\u201d, \u201cInformation\nsociety\u201d and a number of other government programs aimed at the development of\nhigh-tech sectors of the economy; forming a system of development institutions\nin the field of innovations, in particular, for the last five years, the\ncreation of Skolkovo (2010), the Association of Innovative Regions of Russia\n(2010), the Fund for Infrastructure and Educational Programs (2010), the VEB-\nFund Innovations \u201d(2011), Russian Direct Investment Fund (2011), Industrial\nDevelopment Fund (2014), EXIAR OJSC (2014); adoption of a new version of the\nFederal Law \u201cOn Economic Partnerships\u201d, which formulates an agreement on\npartnership management, within the framework of which  necessary conditions and procedures for the creation\nof funds, including  the implementation\nof venture investment, are determined.<\/p>\n\n\n\n

The development of innovation territories (pyramid layer –\ninfrastructure) means financing for the creation in the constituent entities of\nthe Russian Federation of the infrastructure of innovative entrepreneurial\nactivity. In the framework of the Support Program for small and medium-sized\nenterprises in the subjects of the Russian Federation for the period 2010\u20132015.\n8.4 billion rubles were allocated for these purposes; formation of 26 pilot innovation\nterritorial clusters, for the provision of subsidies which provide 1.25 billion\nrubles,  the creation of a special economic\nzone “Innopolis”, the formation of a cost recovery mechanism for the\ncreation of technology  and industrial\nparks; implementation of pilot programs to stimulate the demand for innovative\nsolutions at the regional level, one of the programs is \u201cInnovative\nProcurement\u201d, the goal of which is to increase the volume of procurement of\neffective solutions by companies with state participation.<\/p>\n\n\n\n

The export development and international cooperation (pyramid layer –\nmarkets) embraces the formation of an export support system, including\nhigh-tech products in the \u201cone-stop\u201d mode, allowing Russian exporters and\nforeign buyers to electronically fill in and submit primary documents, the\nformation of mechanisms for cooperation in the field of innovations  with the BRICS countries, organizing an open annual\nforum for all parties interested.<\/p>\n\n\n\n

The development of innovative business (pyramid layer – financing of\ninnovative companies) includes the  creation of the Agency for Strategic Initiatives\nto promote new projects,  the approval of\nthe \u201croadmap\u201d in priority areas of technological development,  information technologies, photonics, the\nproduction of composite materials, biotechnology, engineering and industrial\ndesign, the introduction of innovative technologies in the fuel and energy\nsector, the  approval of the innovative\ndevelopment program of 60 largest state-owned companies, the  adoption of a sectoral plan for import\nsubstitutions in industry, the legislation on the best available technologies\nand the introduction of modern technologies has been predominantly formed [1, P. 231.]<\/p>\n\n\n\n

Comparison of innovative\ndevelopment and the potential of Russia with the countries – leaders and\n\u201cgeeks\u201d of innovation<\/strong>.\nTo analyze the innovative development of Russia, we need an international base\nfor a comparison. In order to get maximum information from such a comparison,\nwe are interested in putting Russia on a par with the following groups of\ncountries: with the countries that are leaders of innovations in order to know\nexactly what is good, what worked and works, with those  ones similar to ours in size and structure of\nthe economy, so that the conclusions are applicable, and with those ones  included in the list of leaders relatively\nrecently, so that the conclusions are relevant.\n\nWe applied the\nfollowing six criteria for selecting countries for comparison: current\nleadership in recognized international innovation development ratings (we took\ninto account our position in the four largest innovation indices \u2014 the Global\nInnovation Index (GII), the Global Competitiveness Index (GCI), The Bloomberg\nInnovation Index (BII) and Forbes World’s Most Innovative Companies (FWMIC). In\naddition, we only considered OECD member countries and partners (40 countries\naltogether), because we want to compare Russia with economically developed\ncountries).  The market is up in the ratings,\nmade over the past five years (for example, China made a spurt up by sixteen\nplaces in the GII index (from 43 in 2010 to 29 in 2015), Great Britain – 12\nplaces, Ireland – by 11 places, Italy – by 7 places, the USA – by 6 places;\nRussia, by the way, made a breakthrough by 16 places – that is, more than all\ndeveloped countries and BRICS countries. Our country showed  an  active participation in international trade in\nintellectual property. We take into account the trade turnover, that is, import\nplus export, based on the fact that countries with a greater turnover are included\nin the global innovative \nenvironment,  the large size of\nthe economy – nominal GDP in US dollars. This criterion allows us to choose for\ncomparison with Russia only large-scale economies that have a corresponding set\nof problems that are not driven by small countries, including the manageability\nof the economic and financial system, often the size territories, population,\netc.,  the three largest economies  – the USA, China and Japan, Russia – on the\n9th place, high level of economic development: nominal GDP in US dollars per\ncapita, Russia – at a modest 58th place,  a certain dependence of the economy on the\nrent received from the export of natural resources. We also selected three\nadditional countries that were not included in the final list because of the\naggregate of the previous selection criteria, but, nevertheless, interesting\nfor us from the point of view of innovative development experience in\nconditions of   the natural rent. These countries are Canada,\nNorway and Chile.\n\n\n\n<\/p>\n\n\n\n

\"\"<\/figure><\/div>\n\n\n\n

The selection\nprocedure and the final list of countries are shown in Figure 7. In each\nsubsequent list, the countries from the previous list change places and are\npartially eliminated, reflecting the accumulated rating on the totality of the\ncriteria. The final list includes 15 countries for comparison – from the USA to\nChile – and the list turned out to be prioritized, that is, the policy pursued\nin the United States is more interesting than the policy in Switzerland,\nSwitzerland is more interesting than the United Kingdom, and etc.<\/p>\n\n\n\n

\"\"<\/figure><\/div>\n\n\n\n

Such a technique\nallows to judge whether a state or a lot of resources are invested by the state\nin each of the layers of the pyramid, since this can be said only in relation\nto other countries. These results can be demonstrated in the form of a \u201cheat\nmap\u201d, where top-down countries are the leaders of innovation (in descending\norder), and from right to left – the layers of the pyramid (from the foundation\nto the top), and the values are painted in the color range from green\n(\u201cexcellent\u201d) to red (\u201closers\u201d with twos and ones).  Figure 9 shows the results for 15 countries of\nour target list and Russia.<\/p>\n\n\n\n

\"\"<\/figure><\/div>\n\n\n\n

Each country has its own\npeculiarities, but in general the legitimacy is obvious: almost all countries\nof the targeted list are \u201cexcellent students\u201d in the layers of institutions and\nmarkets, \u201cgood\u201d in the layers of knowledge, culture, infrastructure and\nfinancing of fundamental research, but remain committed “losers” in\nthe layer of financing commercial projects. That is, countries – leaders of\ninnovation are leaders of the environment but are far from the top of the list\nin terms of financing commercial projects. Interesting exceptions are South\nKorea (\u201cfive\u201d for state financing of commercial projects) and China (low marks\nfor fundamental layers).<\/p>\n\n\n\n

In Russia, which places in the ratings according to the relevant\nindicators are presented in the bottom line of the \u201cheat map\u201d, the situation is\nthe opposite: our country is an absolute honored student of targeted state financing\nof commercial innovative projects, but at the same time has an un-innovative\nenvironment.<\/p>\n\n\n\n

The main directions of\ninnovative policy in Russia and innovations as a lever of influence on the\neconomic well-being of the Russian Federation<\/strong>. Now innovations are the main possible lever of\ninfluence on the long-term growth of economic well-being for Russia, because\nthe possibilities of the rest are significantly limited. In recent years, the\nbasic elements of the national innovations ecosystem have been formed in\nRussia, the implementation of large-scale transformations continues, but it\nshould also be noted that the results achieved do not meet expectations.<\/p>\n\n\n\n

For Russia, in order to reach the world level of innovative development and compete with the leading countries, it is necessary to reform the current innovations policy, \u00a0which must be carried out in accordance with the primary tasks: first, the main task is to optimize the innovations management system \u00a0to improve the coordination of innovations politicians, secondly, the development of common agreed cross-cutting priorities of innovative \u00a0policy, thirdly, the elimination of the reasons for the \u201copenness\u201d of the innovations system (in terms of increasing the return on R & D costs and increasing the quantity, availability and competitiveness of ideas and inventions), fourthly, the introduction of a unified monitoring system of the innovative system, including measures for detailing and introducing a system for monitoring innovations.<\/p>\n\n\n\n

List of sources<\/p>\n\n\n\n

  1. Balikhina N.V., Kosov M.E. Development of investment and innovation processes in the Russian economy. Financial aspect \/\/ M .: UNITY-DAN. – 2014. – P. 231. <\/li>
  2. Economic Bulletin of Russia. 2006: Statistical collection \/ Ed. Col .: A.E. Surinov, I.A. Zbarskaya and others – Moscow: Rosstat, 2006. – P.561.<\/li>
  3. Filimonov F.Yu. The genesis of innovation: the process of the emergence and development of innovation \/\/ Industrial service. – 2015. – \u2116 2 (55). – P. 194-200<\/li>
  4. Foreign trade of the Russian Federation: Statistical compilation: 2007. – M .: Central Bank of the Russian Federation, 2008. – P.282.<\/li>
  5. Gershchenkron A. \u201cEconomic Underdevelopment in the Historical Perspective\u201d (\u201cEconomic Backwardnessin Historical Perspective\u201d) – \/\/ 1962 – \/\/ P.121-155<\/li>
  6. Nekrasov D.A. The development of the theory of innovation. Innovation cycles \/\/ Bulletin of the Samara State University of Economics. – 2010. – \u2116 5 (91). – P. 68-71.<\/li>
  7. Osipov Yu.M. On innovations in general and innovations in modern Russia \/\/ Philosophy of Economics. – 2008. – \u2116 3 (57). \u2013 P. 253-255.<\/li>
  8. World Bank: Statistical Book. – M .: World Statistics, 2012. – P.342-343.<\/li><\/ol>\n\n\n\n
    <\/pre>\n\n\n\n

    <\/p>\n","protected":false},"excerpt":{"rendered":"

    \u0423\u0414\u041a: [338.246.2:001.895] = 111 DOI 10.24411\/2413-046\u0425-2019-14008 Innovations and prospects for the innovative development of the economy in the Russian Federation Mogilevich Ekaterina, Semenov Dmitriy, Financial University under the Government of the Russian Federation, Moscow Scientific advisor, Senior teacher Moiseeva T.V. Summary: The article reveals the essence of innovation performance and its economic implications which ensure […]<\/p>\n","protected":false},"author":2,"featured_media":0,"comment_status":"closed","ping_status":"closed","sticky":false,"template":"","format":"standard","meta":{"spay_email":"","jetpack_publicize_message":"","jetpack_is_tweetstorm":false},"categories":[107],"tags":[152],"jetpack_featured_media_url":"","jetpack_publicize_connections":[],"jetpack_sharing_enabled":true,"jetpack_shortlink":"https:\/\/wp.me\/p7IyHt-2rq","_links":{"self":[{"href":"https:\/\/qje.su\/en\/wp-json\/wp\/v2\/posts\/9388"}],"collection":[{"href":"https:\/\/qje.su\/en\/wp-json\/wp\/v2\/posts"}],"about":[{"href":"https:\/\/qje.su\/en\/wp-json\/wp\/v2\/types\/post"}],"author":[{"embeddable":true,"href":"https:\/\/qje.su\/en\/wp-json\/wp\/v2\/users\/2"}],"replies":[{"embeddable":true,"href":"https:\/\/qje.su\/en\/wp-json\/wp\/v2\/comments?post=9388"}],"version-history":[{"count":1,"href":"https:\/\/qje.su\/en\/wp-json\/wp\/v2\/posts\/9388\/revisions"}],"predecessor-version":[{"id":9399,"href":"https:\/\/qje.su\/en\/wp-json\/wp\/v2\/posts\/9388\/revisions\/9399"}],"wp:attachment":[{"href":"https:\/\/qje.su\/en\/wp-json\/wp\/v2\/media?parent=9388"}],"wp:term":[{"taxonomy":"category","embeddable":true,"href":"https:\/\/qje.su\/en\/wp-json\/wp\/v2\/categories?post=9388"},{"taxonomy":"post_tag","embeddable":true,"href":"https:\/\/qje.su\/en\/wp-json\/wp\/v2\/tags?post=9388"}],"curies":[{"name":"wp","href":"https:\/\/api.w.org\/{rel}","templated":true}]}}